סקירה שהכנתי בנושא בשנת 2018 (חלק מעבודה אקדמית):

Is the DPT covered tax in Australian and UK DTAs?

DTAs are agreements between two states and therefore, like any agreement, it is necessary to examine the text and the intentions of the parties. Thus, the starting point is a review of the relevant articles and definitions of the DTAs between Australia or the UK and other countries. This will be done first by referring to the relevant definitions and articles of the OECD Model Convention (OECD MC)[1].

Relevant articles and rules of interpretation

The relevant Article of the OECD MC is Article 2, which defines the taxes covered by the DTA.  Article 2(1) provides that the DTA applies to taxes on income and capital imposed on behalf of one State or its affiliates, irrespective of the form in which they are imposed. The relevant part of Article 2(2) provides that all taxes imposed on income or capital shall be deemed to be such even if imposed on an element of income or capital. Article 2(3) provides the alternative of specifying taxes to be included in the DTA and Article 2(4) provides that the DTA shall apply also to substantially similar taxes imposed by any of the contracting states after the signing of the DTA.

There is no definition in the OECD MC (or its commentary file[2]) of what is income tax, nor is this defined in the domestic law of most countries. Therefore, this is an interpretative question that will usually be discussed by the judge in the relevant country. However, it seems that there are conventions regarding rules of interpretation of the provisions of the DTA and in particular with respect to Article 2 - these conventions were also expressed in local case law[3].

Among other, it is agreed that the formal name of the tax is not the primary factor for its classification, and that it should be made in accordance with accepted international taxation principles (international language and reliance on courts abroad)[4]. It is also agreed that in accordance with the provisions of the Vienna Convention[5], the classification should be relevant to the date of signing of the relevant DTA[6].

With regard to the interpretation of Article 2(3) and 2(4), Ismer[7] explains that there are two interpretative approaches - the micro-approach according to which the "new" tax in dispute should be examined as one of the specified taxes, and the macro-approach according to which the tax should be examined as appropriate to the principles that emerge from the whole of the taxes specified in Article 2(3). However, he emphasizes that according to both approaches, the classification should be based on the taxes specified in the relevant domestic law. For example, if an Australian income tax is specified, the tax cannot be classified as income tax in an objective and detached manner. Brandstetter[8] points out another peculiarity of Article 2(3), namely that extraordinary new tax cannot be included in a DTA which did not adopted it.

In this context, in Australia, the Federal Court in Virgin[9] stated in obiter regarding the interpretation of Article 2(3) that its preferred interpretation of the term "Australian income tax" was "ambulatory and not static". In the circumstances of the case there, it was held that a capital gains tax is indeed part of the Australian income tax as defined in the DTA with Switzerland.

From the general to the specific:

Australia and UK's DTAs do not generally include the broad definitions in paragraphs 2(1) and 2(2) to the OECD MC but specify taxes such as income tax (and corporate tax) 2(3).

The term "Income Tax" has a globally and domestic accepted meaning and it applies to profits in accordance with the Haig–Simons and with the emphasis of it being imposed on the recipient and not on the payer. The common distinctions between this tax and other taxes are mainly the distinction from tax on wealth or tax on a gifts or tax imposed on gross receipts. It is also common to distinguish between tax and a fine.

In this sense, it appears that if the DPT is not income tax (or corporate tax) specified in the DTAs, it is at least a similar tax in the sense of Article 2 (4). However, in light of its special characteristics, several counter-arguments have arisen, which should be discussed.

The HMRC[10] noted that the DPT is not similar to corporate tax and has unique characteristics such as a different tax rate and a different collection and assessment procedure. This argument is likely to be used by the tax authorities to support the claim that the tax is outside the scope of DTAs.

Ismer[11] and others relate to these claims and argue that they should be rejected because the test is substantive and informal, otherwise it will be very easy for states to avoid their obligations under the DTAs. Examination of the tax (in both countries) shows that it is calculated in the same manner as corporate tax, and the claim that it applies only to part of the income of the taxpayer is also irrelevant because the same is true to taxation of a "real" PE. Ismer also refers to the argument of the different tax rate (with respect to corporate tax) and rejects it on the grounds that there is a consensus that this element is not critical to the classification.

However, it can also be argued that that the difference is actually a penal component that is inherent to the tax component or at least that the two can be separated. In this context it should be noted that the tendency is generally to include the accompanying component save for exceptional cases. The US-Australia DTA[12] is an example of such an exception.

Wagman[13] also refers to a number of unique characteristics of the DPT, and tough in relation to FCT in the US under domestic law, it seems that he reaches a similar conclusion. Some of the arguments he raises for discussion are that this is actually a tax liability on a conceptual income and that is sometimes not taxed by the hands of the income producer .But these are similar to CFC legislation and have already discussed even by court.  In the UK Bricom[14] case, it was held that the provisions of a DTA do not apply to profits resulting from interest payments and attributed up under the UK CFC rules, since the tax was not imposed on interest as defined in the DTA. However, the reasons were not that this is a notional income and the result may have been different if it were argued that the tax on CFC income falls within the scope of Article 7 of the DTA (Business Profits). Moreover, the court noted, in obiter, that the tax under the CFC rules was corporate tax (in the UK sense). 

Notwithstanding, in our case, a further obiter in the judgment there is relevant and that is that the court mentioned that since the UK law gives effect to the provisions of the DTAs, and since the UK law[15] does not refer to "similar taxes" as Art.2(4), similar articles in the UK DTAs has no binding legal force. As detailed below, the question of legal validity is not necessarily relevant to the question of whether similar taxes are included in the DTA and therefore will be discussed separately.

Another argument that arises in this context is that the DPT is mainly an anti-avoidance tool, and therefore the provisions of DTAs do not apply to it anyway. Ismer[16] points out that this question, too, is not relevant to the question of whether the tax is covered under Art.2, and therefore it will also be discussed separately (although maybe this is a semantic issue and it can be argued that theoretically a tax agreed upon that is not supposed to be protected by the provisions of a DTA is not a covered tax).

Conclusion and a possible distinction

Despite some unique characteristics, there seems to be a consensus that the DPT in both countries is a tax that is at least substantially similar to the income tax or corporate tax (in UK and Australia) and therefore according to articles identical to 2(4), is covered by their DTAs. Indeed, it is a tax on diverted profits.

In this context, and even if the result may remain unchanged, I think that it is maybe possible to analyze differently the two taxes:

As stated above, FCT will be granted against the UK tax so one can argue that it is essentially a "residual" tax, which constitutes a punitive component only and therefore is not covered. On the other hand, from the same reason, it can be argued that the fact that a foreign corporation tax credit is been granted, actually indicates that it is essentially a corporate tax and thus covered.

Accordingly, with regard to the Australian tax it can be argued that because it does not allow FCT as well as its high rate, it is essentially a deterrent (like a fine) and therefore not covered. In addition, it can be argued that since the tax is intended to apply only to SGE, it is an extraordinary tax that is not covered (however, on the other hand it can be argued that in view of the high corporate tax rate in Australia, the "Mismatch conditions" are more easily met and thus it is a covered tax).

DPT and "anti-avoidance"

As stated above, the tax in both countries is designed to deal with MNI structures or transactions, which aims at tax reduction (in Australia the DPT was even enacted in the anti-avoidance part (IVA) of the ITAA36[17]).

Therefore, there is an argument that Australia and the UK are not obliged to apply the DTAs provisions in respect of the DPT, since such provisions were not intended to apply in these situations in the first place[18]. This argument is supported by the provisions of sections 9.3-9.5 of the Article 1 Commentaries to the OECD MC (2003) and its position on the application of CFC rules. According to this argument, there is an implied consent in the DTAs that the provisions will not apply in tax avoidance situations, or alternatively, there is "justification" to violate DTAs provisions in these situations.

Such an interpretation is ostensibly required by the provision of Article 31 of the Vienna Convention - according to which treaty should be interpreted in light of the principle of good faith. Thus, this is seen as a correct interpretation or a legitimate goal in the eyes of many. Wells[19], for example, calls for the amendment of the FCT regulations in the US so as to ensure that a credit is given for the DPT to protect UK income tax base from the BEPS.

There are, however, considerable arguments against this approach. First, the OECD position was presented only in 2003 and it has since developed so it is impossible to say that the parties to a DTA signed earlier have implicitly agreed on it. Second, and more importantly, the position of one party to the DTA as to what is tax evasion may not necessarily be accepted as such by the other party. In her book[20], De Pierto points out that the OECD errs twice - when it determines that there is no conflict between a domestic law against tax-evasion and DTAs, and when it fails to state in what situations such legislation can be justified.

Indeed, an example of such a conflict can be found in our case.  What is perceived by one country as an attempt to prevent "diversion of profits" can be interpreted by another state as renunciation of the provisions of the DTA and erosion of its tax base. For example, in the Constructive PE scenario, Country B may think that the taxation of profits is contrary to Article 7 of the DTAs (OECD MC), which states that only PE profits shall be taxed by the source state and Article 5 defines the conditions for the establishment of a PE. The taxation of the "avoided" PE (taxation of company B) by definition does not meet these conditions and therefore constitutes violation of the DTA. Similarly, in the second scenario, states A decision not to allow expenses paid to a related enterprise in another country (low taxed), just because the property for which the expenses were paid was held there due to tax considerations (Materiel Condition), and despite the fact that company B is indeed the legal owner and carries the risks involved in such asset, may constitute violation of Article 9 (Arm's length adjustments). A decision to deny deduction of royalty expenses is de-facto taxation of such royalties, at source, in DPT rate, in possible contravention of Article 12.

This argument is reinforced in light of the existence of the BEPS project of the OECD and the MLI[21].  UK and Australia explicitly admit that they deviate from the project and included reservations[22] to Articles 10, 12-14 (PE -anti abuse PE). Therefore it cannot be said that the conditions for extending the meaning of PE or for denying benefits are in consensus. The fact that Australia does not agree[23] for a binding international arbitration mechanism (Articles 18-26) with regard to part IVA of the ITAA36 (and the fact that it enacted the DPT in this section) indicates that it is aware its unilateral legislation.

Hence, Faulhaber [24]probably rightly indicates that the DPT is not only anti-avoidance tools but rather "offensive tax competition measure".

Unilateralism and International Law

De-Pierto[25], explains that with regard to the treaty override two legal systems must be distinguished - one in which international tax treaties have independent validity and one in which treaties are validated by their adoption by domestic law. In the later, when the legislator intends to enact a law that bypasses a DTA the law cannot be challenged in court. However, she emphasizes that even in such a scenario of "legislative override" a violation of international law exists and "legal injury" and "state responsibility" occurs.

Australia and UK belong to the second legal system[26], and therefore, since it appears that the legislator's intention is clear (to deprive benefits under DTAs), then it will not be possible to challenge the DPT. However, De-Pierto points out that, international law derives its only power from states (in both the systems), and therefore its violation (even by "legislative override") causes serious damage to its validity.

Implications

Tax allocation violation

As discussed above, the imposition of the DPT will often be contrary to the existing provisions of the DTAs (with regard to the taxation of profits, royalties, interest rents, etc.), as long as Australia or UK has no right to tax these profits (or their rights are limited to a certain tax rate). In such situation, and due to the legal status of DTAs in both UK and Australia, as well as the absence of binding dispute-resolution mechanisms in the DTAs (Article 25 is not binding reservations been made to the MLI) - the taxpayer will not be able to find relief.

Double taxation

In the event that tax was imposed by the residence country (in the first scenario above - because there is no "real" PE) or by the source country (in the second scenario - because the income producer is the legal owner and there is some economic substance) – a double taxation will also occur.

Although, in the UK (in contrast to Australia), FCT will be probably granted, there may be exceptions where double taxation will occur there too. This can happen for example when contracting state imposes on some or all of the "profits" its own DPT (or similar tax) and claims that they were diverted from its tax base. In such case, since the HMRC's position is that the DPT is not similar to a corporate tax, it can be assumed that no credit will be given for the foreign DPT.

Scope of the implications

As noted above, another difference between the two countries is the corporate tax rate (20% versus 30%) that affects the "Mismatch Conditions". Therefore, in general, the Australian DPT may create conflict with a wider spectrum of countries (all countries where corporate tax rate is lower than 24%) while, the UK DPT is ostensibly more aimed at tax havens. However, Wegman[27] demonstrates how in some cases it imposition may also create conflict with countries with a higher tax rate such as the US (generally, when according to domestic Transfer Pricing provisions the Contracting State attributes part of the "diverted profits" to a resident company).

Potential reactions of taxpayers

Since the declared purpose of the DPT is to prevent diversion of profits, the first obvious reaction of a MNI is to create a "real" PE in the Target Country or ensure that the group's assets are located there in order to avoid the punitive component. In the case of the Australian DPT, since no FCT will be granted, there is another consideration which is the desire to avoid double taxation.

In both countries, the DPT element of deterrence, as well as the uncertainty of its imposition (due to the conceptual principles it is based on regarding, inter alia when the Material provisions are met), may lead to the creation of a real PE and/or to disposition of assets even where there is no real economic justification to it (i.e., the "Material provision" does not exist). In Australia case, given the risk of double taxation, there is a higher probability of such reaction.

However, it is clear that these considerations can also lead to the opposite reaction - namely, to reduce indirect activity (or marketing activity) in the Target Country in order to prevent any chance for the application of the DPT. This will achieve the opposite goal.

Good example of these possible two reactions can be found in the case of Amazon, which immediately after the introduction of the UK DPT shifted profits from Luxembourg[28] to the UK, but in the context of another tax – new GST legislation which was recently imposed in Australia[29] - decided to block Australian consumers.

Potential reactions of contracting states

In the event of the imposition of the tax in contravention of the DTA - and this seems to be the same as our case - the Contracting State is not obliged to assist in the exchange of information (Article 26) and there is no reason for it to do so. Cerioni[30] indicates that assistance in the transmission of information may be important for the imposition of the DPT as data on market share are usually more easily to the authorities of the Country of residence.

In such case the contracting state is also not obliged to grant FTC for the DPT imposed against its tax. However, such a credit may be granted by virtue of the provisions of domestic law and regardless of the provisions of the DTA. This is a situation that is likely to happen since, as mentioned above, the DPT is regarded as conventional income tax. The reasons for such unilateral FCT may be the legal principle of preventing double taxation or a desire to prevent the transfer of activity to the target country (creating there a real PE). After all even without collecting direct tax, the state of residence benefits from investments or from related taxation and that is why preferential tax regimes exists.

An example of these considerations can be found in the responses in the US to the imposition of the DPT: Some believe that the old regulations on foreign tax credits should be amended to explicitly permit a tax credit[31], some believe that the regulations should be amended for the opposite purpose – to prevent an illegitimate bite (without a minimal Nexus or contrary to the DTA) at the tax base, and some believe that there is no need for a change[32].

Finally, another possible response is the imposition of similar DPTs by other states.  This can be done either in order to bite also the cake of low tax regimes (with international legitimacy from precedents –maybe the case of Australia) or to prevent transfer of investments and activity to the Target Country. In the latter case, only a more aggressive tax will create an effective deterrence balance and the result will be a race to the bottom. Alternatively, different taxes may be imposed. For example, since the DPT is mainly relevant to e US MNI the US can see this it inappropriately and impose taxes that are more oriented to Australia such as steel and aluminum tariffs[33].

Conclusions and a view to the future

 

 

 

 

 



[1] OECD. Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital: Condensed Version 2017. Australia and UK's DTAs usually based on the OECD MC. See for example Australian Tax Office Income tax: Interpreting Australia's Double Tax Agreements, T1 2001/13.

[2] OECD, Commentaries on the Articles of the Model Tax Convention. At: <https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/taxation/model-tax-convention-on-income-and-on-capital-condensed-version_20745419>

[3] See Ostime v. Australian Mutual Provident Society 1960 38 ITR 35 Cal and Thiel v Federal Commissioner of Taxation [1990] HCA 37; 171 CLR 338; 94 ALR 647.

[4] Brandstetter, P. (2010). The Substantive Scope of Double Tax Treaties - a Study of Article 2 of the OECD Model Conventions, Ph.D. WU Vienna University of Economics and Business Avilable at: http://epub.wu.ac.at/2019

[5] Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties on 22 May 1969 – Art 31, 32.

[6] See Cerioni, Luca, 'The New “Google Tax”: The “Start of the End” for Tax Residence as a Connecting Factor for Tax Jurisdiction?', (2015), European Taxation, Vol 55.

[7] Ismer, Roland , Jescheck, Christoph, 'The Substantive Scope of Tax Treaties in a Post-BEPS World: Article 2 OECD MC (Taxes Covered) and the Rise of New Taxes' (2017) 45 Intertax, Issue 5, pp. 382–390.

[8] See 8 above (p 65)

[9] Virgin Holdings SA v Commissioner of Taxation [2008] FCA 1503 (10 October 2008)

[10] See 1 above - in the section dealing with the DPT procedure.

[11] See 11 above – he refer to others (p 386).

[12] Convention between the Government of Australia and the Government of the United States of America for the Avoidance of Double Taxation and the Prevention of Fiscal Evasion with Respect to Taxes on Income, [1983] ATS 16 - in its general definitions section.

[13] Wagman, Philip, 'The U.K. Diverted Profits Tax: Selected U.S. Tax Considerations' (2015) Tax Notes 1413

[14] Bricom Holdings Ltd v Inland Revenue Commissioner, [1997] BTC 471

[15] Section 788 to The Corporation Tax Act 2010 (c.4)

[16] See 11 above.

[17] INCOME TAX ASSESSMENT ACT 1936

[18] See Ross, Lauren Ann, and Samuel M. Maruca. “Through the Looking Glass? The United Kingdom Diverted Profits Tax' ( 2015) Tax Management Memorandum 56 (23): 449.

[19] Wells, Bret, 'The Foreign Tax Credit War', 2016 BYU L. Rev. 1895 (2017). Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.byu.edu/lawreview/vol2016/iss6/10

 

[20] De Pietro, Carla (2012) Tax Treaty Override, [Dissertation thesis], Alma Mater Studiorum Università di Bologna, AT:  <http://amsdottorato.unibo.it/5140/1/carla_depietro_tesi.pdf>

[21] OECD. Multilateral Convention to Implement Tax Treaty Related Measures to Prevent Base Erosion and Profit Shifting done at Paris on 7 June 2017.

[22]Treasury Laws Amendment (Combating Multinational Tax Avoidance) Act 2017.Reservations list: <https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/725261/Final_list_of_UK_reservations_and_notifications_made_on_deposit_of_the_instrument_of_ratification.pdf>

[23] See Explanatory Memorandum, Treasury Laws Amendment (OECD Multilateral Instrument) Bill 2018.

[24] Lilian V. Faulhaber, The Trouble with Tax Competition: From Practice to Theory, 71 Tax L. Rev.

[25] See 24 above.

[26] See 19 above and in Australia s section 4(2) of the International Tax Agreement Act 1953 (Cth).

[27] See 17 above

[28] Roman Lanis, How will Amazon navigate Australia’s taxation system? (October 11, 2017), The Conversation < https://theconversation.com/how-will-amazon-navigate-australias-taxation-system-85323>

[29] The Guardian, Amazon to block Australians from using US store after new GST rules (May 2018) < https://www.theguardian.com/australia-news/2018/may/31/amazon-to-block-australians-from-using-us-store-after-new-gst-rules>

[30] See 10 above.

[31] See 23 above

[32] See J. Clifton Fleming, Jr., Robert J. Peroni & Stephen E. Shay, Two Cheers for the Foreign Tax Credit, Even in the BEPS Era, 91 Tulane L. Rev. 1 (2016).

[33] Nassim Khadem, Potentially dangerous': Ex-US official warns against tax on Amazon, Google (4 June 2018), The Sydney Morning Herald < https://www.smh.com.au/business/the-economy/potentially-dangerous-ex-us-official-warns-against-tax-on-amazon-google-20180604-p4zjdz.html>